Wednesday, September 30, 2009

The leverage cycle , tipping points, black swans and red dragons


Until recently economists were certain that finance has absolutely nothing to offer macroeconomics on the level theory or practice. In the center of economic theory were money supply and interest rates. However In real world when a homeowner takes out a loan and using say a house as collateral, he must negotiate not only just the interest rate, but also how much he can borrow. In other words equally important to interest rate is leverage rate. Let’s take a look on a simple example (I took this example from John Geanakoplos paper The Leverage cycle who together with Hyun Song Shin deserves credit for excellent analysis of leverage and collateral for functioning the financial system)

If the house costs USD100k he borrows USD80k and pay USD20k in cash we say that the collateral rate is USD100k/USD80K=125% the leverage is USD100k/USD20k =5 loan value is USD80k/USD100k = 80%. If then the value of the house raises let say by 20% collateral rate rises to 150%, the loan value drops to 67% and the leverage drops to 4.

In general leverage falls when value of total assets rise. For households, the change in the leverage and change in size of balance sheet size are negatively correlated. However the picture for financial intermediaries is very different. (This is well documented in the series of papers by Hyun Song Shin. Here you can find a link to her web page at Princeton University).


First let’s assume that the bank or other financial intermediary wants to maintain a constant leverage ratio of 10. It keeps securities worth 100 finances is assets with debt worth 90.

--------ASSETS ---LIABILITIES
Securities 100---- 10 Capital
------------------------90 Debt

Now let’s assume that value of securities increases by 1% to 101. Now the balance sheet looks like this:

-------ASSETS ---LIABILITIES
Securities 101 ---11 Capital
-----------------------90 Debt

Leverage drops to 9.18 but the banks wants to keep it constant at 10 and it has to purchase securities worth 9 and finance this purchase with additional debt. Thus, an increase in the price of the security leads to an increased holding worth 9 So the demand curve is upward sloping

---------ASSETS ---LIABILITIES
Securities 110 ---11 Capital
------------------------99 Debt

This mechanism works in reverse too. If now the securities prices fall so the value of assets kept on balance sheet inches down to 109 the leverage now is to high 109 to 10= 10.9. The bank has to adjust down its leverage by selling securities worth 9.

---------ASSETS--- LIABILITIES
Securities 109 ---10 Capital
-------------------------99 Debt

Thus a fall in the price of securities leads to sales of securities which mean that the supply curve is downward sloping. Leverage targeting entails upward sloping demands and downward sloping supplies.
But in real world financial intermediaries are far from being passive in adjusting their balance sheets. Leverage sector (banks, brokerage houses, hedge funds etc.) uses Value at Risk models to adjust their balances sheets. Adrian and Shin showed that procyclical leverage can be traced to the counter-cyclical nature of VaR.



In other words greater demand for the assets tends to put upward pressure on its prices, and then there is a feedback effect in which stronger balance sheets feed greater demand for the asset which in turn raises the asset price and lead to stronger bigger balance sheets. This process if unchecked can lead asset prices up to the shy and then down to the hell (as this process works in reverse too)
(chart reproduced from Adrian and Shin )

That’s why in absence of intervention leverage becomes too high in boom times and too low in bad times (bust). As result , in boom times asset prices are too high, and in crisis time they are too low. This is the leverage cycle.

Eastern Europe boom and bust


Investment bank portfolios are marked to market but the commercial banks balance sheet is not directly affected by changes in asset prices. The reason behind is that usually the biggest item on the balance sheet of commercial banks are loans to consumers (credit) which are not mark to marked. Figure 1 is a scatter chart of the change in leverage and change in total assets of 5 biggest Ukrainian banks (2000-2008). I choose Ukrainian banks as Ukraine and Baltic countries (Lithuania, Latvia, Estonia) suffers in the aftermath of financial crises the worst GDP contraction in whole CEE region. Although I had access only to limited number of observations but most of the observations are concentrated along the vertical line which suggest that Ukrainian commercial banks were targeting constant leverage ratio.



Even in absence of asset price changes (loans, credit) there is potential room for feedback between the balance sheet size and asset prices through shifts in perceived risk.
As I mentioned earlier when the homeowner takes out a loan and using say a house as collateral, he must negotiate not only just the interest rate, but also how much he can borrow. If then the home price increases the collateral ratio raises which may give false impression that the credit risk is falling.








Figure 2 is a chart of average flat prices in capitals of Ukraine (Kiev), and Estonia (Tallinn). I choose home prices as a “natural estimator” of collateral value as credit boom in CEE was mainly driven by surge in number of mortgages. The chart shows that the prices not only raise but also its pace of growth accelerated as time passes reaching maximum in 2008. This was an effect of slowly (at the beginning) accelerating credit growth, which pushes up the collateral ratio and then shifts down perceived risks. Loan officers were more willing to lend as the collateral ratio keep exploding. The more credit was given the higher was the value of collateral the higher was the credit needed for purchasing home which further erodes the lending standards.
Positive feedback process between the credit and collateral value starts slowly at the beginning the credit is soundly based. But as the amount of debt accumulates, total lending increases in importance and begins to have leading appreciable effect on collateral values.






Figure 3 is a chart of commercial bank assets to GDP ratio in Estonia , Poland, and Ukraine. In Estonia and in Ukraine the ratio grows very rapidly which underlines growth of credit in leading role in the process of asset prices/value collateral surge.


Tipping points, Black Swans and Red Dragons


According to standard economic theory markets are fully efficient and only revelation of new important information can cause a crash. But standard economic theory neither can explain creation of the bubbles nor bust of it. The leverage much better explains the economic process of asset price boom and bust. Question is whether it is possible to predict coming asset price bust? According to Nassim Taleb author of famous book “ the black swan” high impact rare events are unpredictable as their share all characteristic of smaller events.

However Didier Sornette in series of papers showed that high impact rare events may be predictable as they belong to a statistical population, which is different from a bulk of the distribution of smaller events, requires some additional amplification mechanism. He argues that extreme events are even “wilder” than predicted by extrapolation of the power law distribution. He calls these outliers a kings or dragons. Emergence of these wild events requires a positive feedback mechanism which leads to increase cooperative of the whole system , leading to development of endogenous instabilities.
(chart reproduced from D.Sornette presentation)





This is complex system approach which is quite different forms “analytical” economics approach which favors decomposing system in components and analyzing it separately to understand the functioning of the whole. “Analytical” approach is destroying information about interactions/linkages between the parts of the system which may lead to some surprising “emergent” properties of the whole.
The emergent property of leverage sector (i.e Banks) comes competition which leads to synchronization of risk exposure. Let’s imagine a borrower who is coming to the bank for mortgage and says that another bank down the block offers him a credit in value of 110% of real estate he wants to buy instead of 50% he is getting here. If the bank would not follow competitors excessive lending policy its balance sheet would not grow fast enough to stop competitors from takeover, management could be replaced for unimpressive profits etc… Pretty soon both banks eases the lending standards which keep feeding positive feedback process from balance sheet size to asset prices.
The process continues until a tipping point is reached where total credit cannot increase fast enough to continue stimulating asset prices but the whole system is sharing similar risk (real estate). At that time system as a whole is very sensitive to even a small shock but the source of the crash lies in its emergent fundamental instability.
This tipping point is analogues of critical points studied in statistical physics and system before reaches that point may sending precursory signals which can be modeled by LPPL(Log –periodic power Laws.)

Read More......

Monday, September 21, 2009

Lehman should not be allowed to fall



I am about to mark the anniversary of the financial meltdown. In September 2008 bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers freeze the global financial system for several weeks. But the fall of Lehman was not the cause of the crises but rather a late symptom of cracks in the financial system caused by very high leverage. Financial intermediaries naturally leverage their balance sheets. But Chart 1 point to a strong positive relationship between changes in leverage and the size in balance sheet size which suggest a high procyclical in the leverage process of financial intermediaries.


Chart 1 reproduced from Hyun Song Shin

In good times leverage and balance sheet size of financial intermediaries increase together when risks decrease measured (VaR). But when the loss distribution is exponential, the behavior of intermediaries conforms to the Value-at-Risk rule, in which exposure is adjusted to maintain a constant probability of default. In a system context, increased risk reduces the debt capacity of the financial system as a whole, giving rise to amplified de-leveraging by institutions through the chain of repo transactions. This process leads to a synchronized contraction of balance sheets which will cause stresses that show up somewhere in the system.



Chart 2 US Fedwired interbank payment network reproduced from K.Soramäki




In case of the financial networks it is crucial for its sustainability to know where the stresses may show up as its topology is highly disassortative. I.E.US FED payment system contains over 9500 participating banks but the core of the network with 66 banks accounts for 75% of the daily transactions. Distribution of the connections between participants in that network follows the power law distributions (few banks are hubs for thousands of others while thousands of banks in that network are only connected to few others).
The good news is that this type of network (scale-free network) is very resilient to accidental failure as random failure even large amount of banks is unlikely to freeze the whole system ( the random failure of banks will take only the small ones as they are much more plentiful than the hubs ).

The Achilles heel of the network is its dependence on hubs (large interconnected banks) . Recent research suggests that generally speaking, that the simultaneous collapse of only of 5-15% of all hubs can crash free scale network. Therefore the protecting the hubs of the system are essential for its functioning. Allowing Lehman to collapse which was a central hub in financial network was clearly against this rule and was a major and cost full mistake.

Conclusions are rather fairly simple:

1) Regulators/central banker should watch and limit the leverage in the financial system (not only target inflation)

2) core of the network should be protected at all cost but also should be subject of stricter regulations

Read More......

Tuesday, September 8, 2009

The Chinese equity bubble - UPDATE

Dieter Sornette and his team just released an updated version of its earlier paper on Chinese equity bubble. This version of the paper includes more details i.e. description of bubble detection tools etc. Link here

Read More......

Thursday, September 3, 2009

World stock market: approaching trend reversal?

Another interesting implementation of LPPL model has been just published today. Stanislaw Drozdz and Pawel Oswiencimka in short paper predict that core stocks indexes will face significant correction. A quote:

Based on our ”finance-prediction-oriented” methodology which involves such elements as log-periodic self-similarity, the universal preferred scaling factor 2, and allows a phenomenon of the ”super-bubble” we analyze the 2009 world stock market (here represented by the S&P500, Hang Seng and WIG) development. We identify elements that indicate the third decade of September 2009 as a time limit for the present bull market phase which is thus to be followed by a significant correction

Read More......

Sugar bubble ready to burst

Over the past few weeks, sugar has been on such upward spiral, hitting a 28-year high. Growing demand in Brazil for sugar to be turned into ethanol, coupled with a sharp fall in Indian and Brazilian production, have both sent sugar prices sky high. Many think that the supply shortfall will extend through 2010. Then from fundamental perspective valuation current sugar valuation may be correct as the supply fall short behind the demand. But to speak of supply and demand as if they were determined by forces that are independent of the market participant’s expectations is quite misleading.

It’s true the situation is not so clear cut in case of commodities where supply is largely dependent on production and demand on consumption. But the price that determines the amounts produced and consumed is not necessarily the present price. On the contrary, the market participants are more likely to be guided by future prices, either as expressed in future markets or as anticipated by themselves. In either case it is inappropriate to speak of independently given supply and demand curves because both curves incorporate expectations about future prices.

Those expectations may become self-referential which will lead to the positive feedback process (the higher the price or the price return in the recent past, the higher will be the price growth in the future). Positive feedbacks, when unchecked, can produce runaways which beyond a certain point become unsustainable ending in crash. In short LPPL models developed by Sornette aims, at detecting the transient phases where positive feedbacks operating on some markets or asset classes create local unsustainable price run-ups. The result of the analysis is summarized bellow in figure 1.



I analyzed sugar#11 future time series between September 2007 and September 3 2009. The y axis is logarithmically scaled so that the exponential function would appear as a straight line. LPPL fit exhibit upward curvature which is clear evidence that the prices were growing “super-exponentially”. The projected crash dates are September 5-15 .It must be noted that a good fit of the model to the data series is not a 100% certainty for a crash, but it clearly points at a bubble formation.

Read More......